Смекни!
smekni.com

Options For Electoral College Essay Research Paper (стр. 2 из 2)

thrive and attract exactly as many voters as they actually represent the beliefs

of, because you have no fear of losing your vote to a “spoiler” if your second

or third choice is a mainstream candidate. This reduces apathy. Primary

elections become completely unnecessary: a party can run all its candidates at

once and the strongest of the group will get almost all of that party’s votes in

the final count. Elections in general will be driven more by people’s

preferences on issues than by loyalty to parties. We could well see more

candidates running as independents and being elected. The election season

could be significantly shortened. No voter would be frozen out of the

pre-selection process within a party because of variations in state laws. The

House of Representatives or other mechanism for resolving the lack of a true

majority has no possible role except in a rare case where the vote is split so

deeply that even people’s third and fourth choices don’t produce a winner.

This is pretty much impossible where ideological camps are divided into Left

and Right; it might happen if we had Left, Right, Up, and Down factions all

incompatible with the other three, but that’s hardly likely to happen.

Disadvantages: the ballot itself would be more complicated. The counting

process would have to be modernized and made a good deal more

sophisticated and reliable. (But then, the 2000 election makes it clear that we

have to replace a lot of bad voting equipment already.) We would probably

need voting machines that have good preventive interlocks to reduce mistakes

that would invalidate ballots, or there would be a lot more such mistakes

made by voters. (Again, this probably needs doing anyway.) In any

jurisdiction where we don’t have such modernization, the counting process

would be prolonged and tedious. There would always be a tradeoff to make

between having the voters make more secondary choices (fifth best, sixth

best, and so on) which would improve certainty when there are lots of

candidates, vs. limiting the number of secondary choices in order to reduce

the data processing burden on vote counters. (And if we ask for more

secondary choices, a lot of voters probably won’t make them; they’ll vote for

the two or three they like and cast no votes for the others.) A disadvantage

that has been claimed for this system is that there are obscure strategies by

which clever enough voters can actually hurt a candidate’s changes by giving

him a higher vote, but I don’t think this would apply if people were ranking

only their top few choices. It also tends to generate a lot of backroom

horse-trading between various factions over who they will endorse as second

choices, but I don’t think that’s necessarily a bad thing. But as with a pure

popular vote, one big disadvantage is that this undoes the weighting by states

that the electoral college has, which means small states probably won’t pass

it.

PREFERENTIAL POPULAR VOTE POINT-COUNT (THE BORDA

SYSTEM). This is a variation of preferential voting in which, if there are

(say) six preferential rankings on each ballot, a candidate gets six points for

being picked first, five for being picked second, and so on. The candidate

picked last gets one point. The winner is the one with the highest total point

count.

Advantages: like preferential voting only with considerably faster and simpler

counting procedures.

Disadvantages: unfortunately, this system gives voters a considerable

incentive to rank candidates who are threats to their first choice much lower

than they would deserve based on the issues. For instance, if voters for one

mainstream party candidate want to make sure their man beats the other

candidate from the same party, they would rank the other guy lower than the

opposition party candidates. If enough voters act this way, fringe candidates

with no true mandate end up getting greatly inflated vote totals and could

conceivably even win.

WEIGHTED PREFERENTIAL POPULAR VOTE. We could make the

preferential system compatible with the electoral college’s protection of

smaller states by giving each state a weighting factor to multiply its vote

totals by, as in the weighted popular vote system. Or we could toss

winner-take-all fake vote blocks by state into the mix, though I figure this

would make an awkward and ugly fit with a preferential system.

Advantages: all those of preferential voting, plus protection of small states as

under the existing system, and therefore much better likelihood of being

approved.

Disadvantages: overtly spelling out in law that one person’s vote counts for

more than another’s is bound to get people irked. State winner-take-all blocks,

on the other hand, introduce a non-preferential element, and increase the

chances that the majority winner is not selected correctly according to

people’s real rankings of the choices. As with any preferential system, the

ballot and the counting are more complex and therefore would have to be

more computerized than they are now.

PREFERENTIAL ELECTORAL VOTE. This is an attempt to introduce

the advantages of the preferential method into the electoral college. The

voters in each state would cast preferential ballots. The state would award its

electoral votes according to the first choice vote count. If nobody got a

majority of the electoral college, the votes of losing candidates would be

transferred to those voters’ secondary choices, and the electoral vote would be

recomputed. Electoral votes would have to be awarded proportionally by each

state, not by winner-take-all, because if winner-take-all was used, the

preferential part would quite likely never get to operate. With a variation of

this scheme — have each state use a preferential system to select its electoral

votes, instead of using the second place votes only when there is no electoral

majority — you could implement this system without a constitutional

amendment. Even the first version might just possibly be able to be

shoehorned into the space allowed by the present constitution, if the Supreme

Court would allow each state to make its final choice of electors based on

vote totals announced by the other states.

Advantages: retains most of the benefits of a preferential system with less

disruption of the status quo, and probably less contention over the state

weighting issue. Proportional electoral voting does not create the high risk of

there being no majority winner as it would in a non-preferential system, if

you use the stronger version that probably requires an amendment.

Disadvantages: basically, this is at best not much more than an inaccurate

way of doing weighted preferential popular votes; the electoral college

apparatus is pretty much just nonfunctional window dressing. Or, if this is

implemented in the toned-down form without an amendment, states might

want to award their electoral votes winner-take-all, which would re-introduce

a lot of inaccuracy into the process.

POPULAR APPROVAL VOTE. This is a new addition to the list — a

system I had not heard of when I wrote the first version of this document.

Approval voting consists of giving a “yes” vote for every candidate that you

can stand, and a “no” vote for all those you can’t. In essence, you can vote for

as few or as many of the candidates as you wish. It’s like preferential voting

except without a hierarchy of individual ranking. The winner is the candidate

with the most total “yes” votes. State weighting could be applied, or not, the

same as with preferential popular voting, with about the same consequences.

Advantages: the same advantages as the preferential system, and it’s simpler,

imposing no extra difficulties with counting or requiring new fancy voting

machinery. Split vote problems are eliminated, primaries and two-party

constraints are eliminated, everybody can vote for who they really like best,

and the one who is most broadly acceptable wins.

Disadvantages: unlike the preferential system, this one does not distinguish a

ringing mandate from bare tolerance. It gives less of a mandate on issues than

a preferential system does. One can’t help but suspect that winning candidates

will tend to be bland mediocrities… though in practice I suppose this system

will probably elect the same person that a preferential vote would. Still,

voters would probably be happier and feel more engaged if they could

indicate which candidate they really like vs. which they find merely

acceptable. Because of this, any really partisan voter might feel motivated to

vote “no” for all candidates but one, just to make their preference clear,

thereby increasing the likelihood that the winner would have no majority. In

short, it’s difficult to come up with anything very solid as a disadvantage for

this system… all I’ve got here is either subjective, speculative, or just a minor

nit.

APPROVAL BASED ELECTORAL VOTE. This is another one that

could be implemented without an amendment. The electoral votes of each

state would go to whoever got the most approval votes in that state, or could

be split proportionally among candidates according to their approval vote

totals.

Advantages: similar to those of the non-amendment version of the

preferential electoral vote. Voters would get to vote for who they really liked,

and there would be no need for primaries and no obstacles to third parties.

Disadvantages: Without an amendment, proportional assignment of electoral

votes would leave considerable risk of nobody winning an electoral vote

majority. You could have ten candidates with handfuls of electoral votes

apiece. Winner-take-all assignment of states’ votes would perpetuate errors

and distortions of the outcome, without fully eliminating that risk. A pure

approval vote always has a winner, but combining the results of separate

approval votes by state no longer has this advantage. This could send third

party candidates back to the ghetto of being “spoilers” once they become

strong enough to win a few states. A preferential system, if imposed in the

more sweeping way that would require an amendment, could eliminate this

problem even if the electoral college is still used; an approval system cannot

do so.

In conclusion, I think it’s obvious that I would strongly prefer either some

kind of preferential system or a popular approval vote. Any other leaves the

majority of the current shortcomings unresolved. I think a lot more voters

would end up happy with the way they were voting, and we’d have far less

apathy. I think my preference of the systems listed here would be a pure

preferential popular vote, or maybe a weighted one (though of course as a

Californian I can hardly embrace weighting wholeheartedly).

I think the data processing challenges that a preferential system would bring

are entirely manageable, even if voters end up casting many ranking votes.

Each precinct would, instead of submitting a total for each candidate, submit

a table listing votes for each permutation of preference order. The amount of

data would be much larger than what is needed today, but would still be

manageably sized — a paper printout of it could fit into a manila folder if the

voters rank the top eight candidates. (It gets more like milk-crate sized if we

allow nine or ten rankings.) Once such tables are combined at a county or

state level, the translation of secondary votes could proceed without any

further reexamination of the ballots. But if a precinct has inadequate data

processing gear to produce and transmit these large result tables, they’d be

forced to repeatedly recount all the ballots as losing candidates are eliminated

one by one. The burden could be minimized if voters only mark their top two

or three or four choices, but this slightly increases the likelihood of the

winner not showing a true majority.

One person objected that if we had a constitutional amendment describing

such a system, it would be as big as the rest of the constitution. I think it

could be described in general terms in about the amount of text that the

twelfth amendment uses, with the details being left up to congress. Another

common objection seems to be that voters would be annoyed and confused

by such a complex system. But as far as I have been able to learn, when the

system has been tried on a small scale by a few U.S. cities such as

Cambridge MA, people are usually pleased with it.

I also think that almost any of the above would be better than the existing

system.

If none of these national reforms gets accomplished, one positive step I’d like

to work toward is to get the state of California (where I live) to allocate its

electoral votes proportionally. Having such an enormous block of votes be

awarded winner-take-all is just far too unfair both to other states, and to the

millions of voters on the losing side within the state. It is, I believe, a major

contributor to voter apathy. Some may say that this would, at present, be to

the advantage of the Republicans, but in many other times it would have

helped the Democrats, so I think the idea can be considered on its merits for

the long term in a nonpartisan way. The fact that the state is genuinely split

between left and right and is not dominated over the long term by either party

(as are New York and Texas, the other two most populous states) also means

that such a reform has a real chance of being passed. No state where the party

in power always gains by winner-take-all would want such a change. Unless

maybe, just possibly, you could persuade the New York democrats and the

Texas republicans to make a trade, since the effect of both doing it together

might come out pretty much neutral. But California is the place to start.